[Second in a four-part series. Click here for Part One. Click here for Part Three Click here for Part Four
In
part one of this series, we argued that anarchy is the solution to the problem
of oligarchic control of democratic institutions. This holds true for economic institutions
as well. And no better example can be provided than Obama’s sinister
Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), which is designed in neoliberal fashion to
financially reward the 1 percent on Wall Street and the 1 percent
internationally, because it is all about the international elite, not just the
average people in the United States who are expendable under the TPP
arrangement. Obama knows this.
We argue that it is not just anarchism that will
salvage democratic institutions, but also a Marxist economic vision that
refuses to allow workers in the United States and international community to be
exploited. Marx was correct when he argued that capitalism rests essentially on
the exploitation of the working class. The problem remains one of conflict
between labor and capital, which people like Paul Krugman the Keynesian and journalists
like Chris Matthews the liberal refuse to acknowledge. The TPP is not some
Greek tragedy where the actors are blind to their own demise; rather, they know
completely what the outcomes are going to be for themselves at the expense
others.
Read Development, Democracy and
Welfare States: Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe by Stephan
Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman (2008)—they saw this coming. This is the motive
for Occupy and why the oligarchy has got to go. What this form of globalization
accomplishes is simply a reinforcement of neocolonialism and neoimperialism. In
the third part of this series, we will pull apart the TPP, which is nothing
more than NAFTA on meth. The following is our continuation of why oligarchies
are perpetuated in democratic institutions.
Domination and Control of Institutions
Individuals
who have ultimate authority in an organization are the ones who have the final
decision-making power over the organization's system of rewards or punishments,
its budget and personnel, its policies and property. This means that
enforceable authority has the power to exclude others from control over it.
Organizational proprietors exercise “ultimate authority” and are invested, not
solely by tradition or sentiment, but by state charter with the right to deal
with the organization's incorporated resources. Directors, trustees, and owners
exercise power either by occupying the top positions in which ruling decisions
are made or by hiring and firing those who do. William Domhoff asserts that:
“…control is in the hands of the board of directors, a group of men
usually numbering between ten and twenty-five who meet once or twice a month to
decide upon the major policies of the company. In addition … the board always
includes at least the top two or three officers in charge of day-to-day
operations … We consider the boards decisive because, despite the necessity of
delegating minor decisions and technical research, they make major decisions,
such as those of investment, and select the men who will carry out daily
operations. In fact, their power to change management if the performance of the
company does not satisfy them is what we … mean by control.”
Consequently,
Michael Walzer observes that the directors of most organizations:
“…preside over what are essentially authoritarian regimes with no
internal electoral system, no opposition parties, no free press or open
communications network, no established judicial procedures, no channels for
rank-and-file participation in decision making. When the state acts to protect
their authority, it does so through the property system, that is, it recognizes
the corporation as the private property of some determinate group of men and it
protects their right to do, within legal limits, what they please with their
property. When corporate officials defend themselves, they often involve
functional arguments. They claim that the parts they play in society can only
be played by such men as they, with their legally confirmed power, their
control of resources, their freedom from internal challenge, and their ability
to call on the police.”
The
boards of directors of most business firms do not exercise a “collegial” power except in the formal, legal
sense. In other terms, even among themselves directors seldom operate
democratically since usually one or two of them enjoy a preponderant influence
over the corporation. Bruce Berman notes that private power is exercised both “in
the economy and society” through “organizations whose internal political
processes are, with few exceptions, authoritarian, oligarchic and devoid of any
democratic procedures or controls.” Where the board of directors consists of
corporate employees dependent on the president for career advancement, the
board simply reaffirms past decisions or presents modest but inconsequential
changes. Top corporate managers, themselves board members and large
stockholders, are the active power within a firm, selecting new members,
exercising a daily influence over decisions, and enjoying a degree of
independence. This same scenario can easily be translated into nonprofit
institutions, education, churches, government, unions, administration and
policy. Furthermore, the institutionally controlled roles are themselves so
legitimized by practice and custom, that the coercive element of this
oligarchic arrangement is in effect disguised.
It
appears evident, at least from what has been discussed, that authority is
delegated downward within an organizational system and institutional structure
and that it is extended, in anti-democratic fashion, in order to better serve
those at elevated levels. Ralf
Dahrendorf states, “For the bureaucrats the supreme social reality is their career
that provides, at least in theory, a direct link between every one of them and
the top positions which may be described as the ultimate seat of authority. It
would be false to say that the bureaucrats are a ruling class, but in any case
they are part of it, and one would therefore expect them to act accordingly in
industrial, social and political conflicts.” Rousseau refers to people in this
elite category as persons “hurried on by blind ambition, and, looking rather
below than above them, come to love authority more than independence, and
submit to slavery, that they may in turn enslave others.” Interestingly enough,
Adam Smith also identifies this anti-egalitarian tendency when he states, “All
inferior shepherds and herdsmen feel the security of their own herds and flocks
depends upon the security of those of the great shepherd or herdsman; that the
maintenance of their lesser authority depends upon that of his greater
authority, and that upon their subordination to him depends his power of
keeping their inferiors in subordination to them.”
The
monopolization of privileged positions and scarce resources by the hierarchical
elite in an organization is justified by the claim that only experienced
persons or trained experts have the expertise to participate in
decision-making. However, Francis Rourke and Glen Brooks state the
organizations and institutions are, “often forced to put on a dramatic show of
scientific objectivity in its budgeting process in order to justify its
requests for continued support, even though the dramatic props - elaborate
formulas, statistical ratios, and so on - may have little to do with the way in
which decisions are actively made within the … establishment.” Thus, modern
hierarchical organization with its elaborate stratification of command and
fragmentation of tasks may itself be less the outgrowth of technical necessity
and more a means whereby the few control the many. Consequently, Michels argues that the
bureaucratic structure within organizations has two main functions: efficiency
and class domination. The former is admitted, open and manifest; the later
covert, unrecognized (by many) and unadmitted. In this sense, class conflict
declines with the growth of bureaucracy, not because bureaucracy's efficiency
and productivity satisfies potential dissenters, but because the structural features of bureaucracy
stifle the power resources of potential dissenters. It would therefore be
correct to say that bureaucratization is another form of class conflict, a form
in which one side wins and the other loses—and which might better be called
class domination.
Organizations and Their Enlightened Self-Interest
Most
organizations, arguably, are linked by a commonality of class interest. The
common misunderstanding is to treat the diversity of organizations as a
manifestation of the diffusion of power. Robert Lynd states that, “sheer
multiplicity of organizations in society may not be assumed to indicate their
discreteness and autonomy …” More often than not, the interaction of power between
organizations and institutions is neither voluntary nor equal, since some
institutions “occupy positions of established dependence upon other
institutions.” This presupposes a distribution of power that some organizations
possess more than others. Consequently, the resources of power are not randomly
scattered among the population to be used in autonomous ways, but are
distributed within a social system, and the way the system is organized has a
decisive effect on what resources are available to whom. Any delineation of the
resources of power would include property, wealth organization, social
prestige, social legitimacy, number of adherents, various kinds of knowledge
and leadership skills, access to technology, control of jobs, control of
information, manipulation of symbolic expressions, and the ability to apply
force and violence. Thus, if organizations and institutions have power as their
major interest, and the maintenance of a class dominated society, then it can
logically be concluded that there are elements in society that lack power.
Lacking accessibility to power resources, certain classes of people will
chronically gain a deficient share of necessities. These people, mostly
children in the United States, do not participate as decision makers in most of
the arrangements directly affecting their lives. They have no lobbies, no voice
in the political system, no appeal from the vested interests of certain adults.
The elderly, women, handicapped, and people of color, at least those in lower
social classes, can be considered among the powerless in society as well.
Every
privileged class tends to propagate the notion that the existing social system
constitutes the natural order of things. In this way, those elite members of
organizations give legitimacy and permanence to their position. These elites,
according to Weber, intend “to have their social and economic positions ‘legitimized.’
They wish to see their positions transformed from a purely factual power
relation into a cosmos of acquired rights, and to know that they are thus
sanctified.” The legitimating myths, or “status-legends” serve not only to
bolster the self-esteem and soothe the conscience of the elite within
organizations, but reinforce the important function of assigning an almost divine
status to class dominance and the rule of elites within organizations. Rousseau
captures this same idea when he states that “the strongest is never strong
enough to be always master, unless he transforms his strength into right, and
obedience into duty.” This can be seen in present day capitalist societies;
profit and property are represented as serving not only the owning class but
also all citizens. What corporations do for themselves is said to benefit the
entire “Free World.” In the German
Ideology Marx identified this tendency in which every group seeks to give “its
ideas the form of universality and [attempts] to present them as the only
rational and universally valid ones.” Both Marx and Engels held that throughout
history, and in particular the historical development of capitalism, that government
had been controlled by key capitalists and their allies, and thus the state in
effect serves as the “executive committee” of the ruling and exploiting class.
In a
society based on acquisition and competition, people acting in their
self-interest do not readily sacrifice their own class advantages out of regard
for the needs of others. Any notion of justice, based on utility maximizing, is
not likely to compel “individual actors” to cast aside their own privatized
pursuits. The history of class divided societies offers little hope to those
who do not share in the relative access of resources in the midst of scarcity.
In the absence of its natural defenders the interest of the excluded is always
in danger of being overlooked according to both Mill and Marx. Theorists such
as Lindblom and Woodhouse state that the common understanding is that, “the
fundamentals of the existing system of wealth and privilege ought not be
challenged.” Moreover, borrowing from Lenin’s critique of Western imperialism,
Martin Luther King in the “Letter from Birmingham Jail,” concludes that “history
is the long and tragic story of the fact that privileged groups seldom give up
their privileges voluntarily.” And Obama has become a team player for the
privileged elite because of the TPP treaty.
Thus,
the threatened loss of power in organizations, and the tendency toward a more
equal distribution of wealth and privilege, is seen not merely as a material
loss, but as the cataclysmic undoing of all social order. Operating on the
assumption that all distribution must be competitive rather than communal, the
elite anticipate - correctly - that more material resources for the
marginalized will only mean less for themselves, since a fundamental reordering
of social priorities would entail a marked diminution of class privileges for
the elite. Within this social and economic setting the reality of conflict is
spawned and determined, according to Marx, precisely because “men make their
own history; but they do not make it just as they please; they do not make it
under circumstances chosen by themselves, but under circumstances directly
encountered, given, and transmitted from the past.” Here Rousseau and Marx
agree, arguing that the elite of any organization enjoy their status “only in
so far as others are destitute of it.
Because, without changing their condition, they would cease to be happy
the moment the people ceased to be wretched.” Consequently, Rousseau argues
that “we find our advantage in the misfortune of our fellow-creatures, and the
loss of one man almost always constitutes the prosperity of another.” Noam
Chomsky even goes so far as to state that organizations such as these are
“designed to undermine democratic decision making and to safeguard the matters
from market discipline. It is the poor and defenseless who are to be instructed
in these stern doctrines.”
Oligarchy as the Iron Law
Weber
examines the relationship between democracy and bureaucratic organizations and
discovers a paradoxical relationship between the two institutions. Some legal
requirements further democracy as well as bureaucracy, such as, the principle
of “equal justice under the law.” This would also include technical and
scientific knowledge rather than arbitrary decisions. Nevertheless, according
to Weber, “‘democracy’ as such is opposed to the ‘rule’ of bureaucracy, in
spite and perhaps because of its unavoidable yet unintended promotion of
bureaucratization.” A major reason for this is that bureaucracy concentrates
power in the hands of those in charge of the bureaucratic apparatus and thereby
undermines democracy. Robert Michels, in Political
Parties, also argues from another perspective, that a number of complex
tendencies in organizations oppose the realization of democracy. He postulates
that democracy leads to oligarchy and consequently the elite domination of
policy outcomes. Michels goes on to state, “It follows that the explanation of
the oligarchical phenomenon which thus results … from the consolidation of
every disciplined political aggregate … reduced to its most concise expression,
the fundamental sociological law of political parties (the term ‘political’
being here used in its most comprehensive significance) may be formulated in
the following terms: ‘It is organization which gives birth to the dominion of
the elected over the electors, of the manditaries over the mandators, of the
delegates over the delegators. Who says
organization says oligarchy.’”
Michels’
thesis in the “iron law of oligarchy,” challenges Rousseau's concept of direct
popular rule and both Madison and Jefferson’s representative form of democracy.
The dysfunctional nature of existing democracy, for Michels, is not simply the
result of social and economic underdevelopment and alienation, inadequate
education, media control of propaganda advertisements, or the capitalist
control of government organizations and institutions. Rather, the problem of
democracy is rooted in its organic nature, and according to Michels’ logic, any
organization must confront its tendency to be controlled at the top. He states,
“The formation of oligarchies within the various forms of democracy is the
outcome of organic necessity, and consequently affects every organization.”
This phenomenon, for Michels, is an intrinsic dimension of bureaucracy and any
large-scale organization or institution. As a result, “Every party organization
represents an oligarchical power grounded upon a democratic basis. We find everywhere
electors and elected. Also we find everywhere that the power of the elected
leaders over the electing masses is almost unlimited. The oligarchical
structure of the building suffocates the basic democratic principle.” Thus
large-scale social organizations and democracy are incompatible, which is
position similar to Lowi’s notion that elitist interest-group liberalism
undermines democracy and Olson's theory that large groups fail to identify and
act on their self-interest, reinforce Michels’ position that the elite emerge
from democratic dysfunction to dominate organizations. Michels found that even
socialist organizations and trade unions that valued democracy could not pursue
their goals, even with strong leadership. From this Michels proposed a general
law that “the majority of human beings … are predestined by tragic necessity,
to submit to the dominion of a small minority, and must be content to
constitute the pedestal of an oligarchy.”
The
underlying notion of a liberal democracy is that government organizations and
institutions are to be administered in a democratic fashion by majority rule,
respect for minority rights, freedom of speech and dissent, based on a
constitutional framework. On the other hand, while democratic values and
policies are to be implemented, the task must be implemented through the most
efficient and effective administrative methods available. Therefore agencies,
governed primarily by the principle of efficiency and effectiveness, tend to
act in an autocratic fashion. Nevertheless, if Michels’ argument is a sound
one, then the implications for government are startling: organizations and their subsequent policies are held captive by an
elite clientele. The reality of an elite ruling government agencies, and
for that matter, political parties, unions, religious organizations, etc.,
conveys the idea that popular rule is subverted. This leaves little doubt
organizations and institutions by their very nature are predisposed inherently to being co-opted by an elite faction. Thus organizations and institutions are
designed to serve the interests of an elite cadre and not its rank and file
members.
In summary, the “iron law of oligarchy,” with
respect to democratic organizations and policy outcomes, functions in four
different capacities. Organizations and policy outcomes: (1) mobilize the
forces of indoctrination and formal socialization in the direction of
established interests and dominant values; (2) control the means of rewards and
punishments based on organizational structures and behavior; (3) preempt
competing behavioral forms and thus structure the definition of “reality” to
the advantage of the elite; and, (4) reinforce their own existence by
preventing any question or ideological challenge to its purpose and mission.
Thus Michels believed that any organization or political system, democratic or
egalitarian, becomes oligarchic and therefore undemocratic.
Edward Martin is Professor of Public Policy and Administration, Graduate Center for Public Policy and Administration at California State University, Long Beach, and co-author of Savage State: Welfare Capitalism and Inequality.
Mateo Pimentel is an Axis of Logic columnist, living on the US-Mexico border. Read the Biography and additional articles by Axis Columnist Mateo Pimentel.
© Copyright 2015 by AxisofLogic.com
This material is available for republication as long as reprints include verbatim copy of the article in its entirety, respecting its integrity. Reprints must cite the author and Axis of Logic as the original source including a "live link" to the article. Thank you!
|